In 1759 Adam Smith, then a thirty-six year old Professor of
Moral Philosophy at Glasgow University, published his Theory
of Moral Sentiments. This work attracted the attention of the
guardians of the immensely wealthy Duke of Buccleuch towards
retaining its author as a tutor to the youthful Duke whilst on a
protracted, and hopefully educational, "Grand Tour" of
continental Europe.
Whilst acting as tutor from 1763 Smith found some of the
time spent in the French provinces hard to fill and seems to have
begun his masterpiece An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of
the Wealth of Nations, as a way of taking up otherwise idle
hours in the summer of 1764. Overall however he derived much
personal philosophical benefit from these months of journeying on
the continent. In Paris he met amongst others, the "Physiocrat"
economic theorist (and court Physician) Quesnay and the French
Ministers, Turgot and Necker.
French economic policy in these times was conducted in
accordance with the "Mercantilism" that had held sway in the
economic thinking of Europe for some three centuries.
Mercantilism expected that governmental control would be
exercised over industry and trade in accordance with the theory
that national strength (i.e. the Royal states treasury) is
increased by a preponderance of exports over imports.
By nature, then, as now, France was fitted to be a great
agricultural country, a great producer and exporter of corn and
wine; but her legislators for several generations had endeavoured
to counteract the apparently natural bias of French economic life
towards agriculture, and had tried to make her an exporter of
manufactured goods.
Like most legislators in those times, they had been
prodigiously impressed by the ambitious position which the
maritime powers, as they were then called (the comparatively
little powers of England and Holland), were able to take in the
politics of Europe. They saw that this influence came from
wealth, that this wealth was made in trade and manufacture, and
therefore they determined that France should not be behindhand,
but should have as much trade and manufacture as possible.
Accordingly, they imposed prohibitive or deterring duties on the
importation of foreign manufacturers; they gave bounties to the
corresponding home manufactures.
Smith found that the French Physiocrats delighted in
attempting to prove that the whole Mercantilist structure of the
French laws upon industry was utterly wrong; that the
prohibitions ought not to be imposed on the import of foreign
manufacturers; that bounties ought not to be given to native
ones; that the exportation of corn ought to be free; that the
whole country ought to be a fiscal unit; that there should be no
duty between any province; and so on in other cases. Smith found
much that he admired in the Physiocrats outlook but he did not
share it completely. Amongst other things the Physiocrats saw
land as the primary source of wealth (one seed sown might produce
twenty at harvest!) rather than manufacturing.
On the completion of his duties as tutor Smith then
returned, after some further months spent in London, to Scotland
where he stayed quietly with his mother at his native town of
Kirkcaldy and occupied himself in study and writing. It was to be
in 1776, that Adam Smith finally saw his "Wealth of Nations"
through the press.
An Inquiry into the Nature and
Causes of the Wealth of Nations
Adam Smith's "Wealth of Nations" is regarded as having been the
first great work of Political Economy. It is in some ways an
enhancement of his "Theory of Moral Sentiments" in that it
focuses on the problems of how people express their self-interest
and their morality. Adam Smith attempted to trace the immediate
expression of human activity and to suggest how this would change
society.
It opens with a most dramatic recommendation of the adoption
of practices which saw work being performed as a number of tasks
that were each alloted, as specialisations, to individual
workers. Smith suggested that a pin factory that had adopted such
a "division of labour" might produce tens of thousands of pins a
day whereas a pin factory in which each worker attempted to
produce pins, from start to finish, by performing all the tasks
associated with pin production would produce very few pins.
In an outline that seems to prefigure Karl Marx'
"materialist conception of history" that appears later in his
"Wealth of Nations" Smith suggests that society has moved through
a number of phases - men once lived by hunting, then developed
nomadic systems of agriculture, then settled farming under the
sway of local feudal manor houses, and then emerged a system of
commercial interdependence. Smith suggested that in each of these
phases society had developed institutions appropriate to that
phase. This development in society and its institutions being at
all times prompted by interplays of self-interest and
morality.
According to Smith the institutions most appropriate to a
period of commercial interdependence would provide for the
governing authority to pursue a laissez faire (let alone) policy
in relation to the economy. Smith justified this by arguing that
people, through applying their talents and assets where they
contributed to the production of the things potential buyers
wanted, sought to earn monies. Under laissez faire systems
individuals, acting in their own self-interest as economic
agents, would tend to dedicate themselves to those economic
activities that brought them the greatest reward in terms of
income be it in the form wages, rent, or profit. Smith showed
that by giving themselves to such highly rewarding economic
activities in their own self interest people would also be
maximising the economic well-being of society.
Smith saw people as economic agents being as it were guided
by an "invisible hand" (a term first used in his Theory of Moral
Sentiments). High prices (in terms of a "natural" price related
to the costs of production) of any good or service would
automatically induce people to engage in its production.
Increased production would lead to a greater supply and lower
prices. People as buyers would get more of what they wanted more
cheaply. People as producers would tend to be earning enhanced
wages as a result of producing the formerly high priced good or
service. A reversal of the argument would see "low" priced items
falling away in terms of their production.
Smith saw in the division of labor and the extension of
markets almost limitless possibilities for society to expand its
wealth through manufacture and trade. Wealth consists of the
goods which all the people of society consume; note all - this is
a democratic, and hence radical, philosophy of wealth. Gone is
the notion of gold, treasures, kingly hoards; gone the
prerogatives of merchants or farmers or working guilds. We are in
the modern world where the flow of goods and services consumed by
everyone constitutes the ultimate aim and end of economic
life.
Although Economics has moved on in many was from the outlook
and policies endorsed in the Wealth of Nations that epoch-making
publication remains as perhaps the most famous economics book of
all time. Governments in search of a strengthening of their
states through economic policy, and many individuals in search of
personal gain, have all drawn lessons from its pages. Powerful
movements that led to the emergence of Modern Capitalism were
substantially based on Smith's work and hence he deserves to be
regarded as one of the most dramatically influential philosophers
or philosophic writers of modern times.
|